Namespaces
Variants
Actions

Difference between revisions of "Pareto, Vilfredo Federigo Samaso"

From Encyclopedia of Mathematics
Jump to: navigation, search
m
(accents)
 
(6 intermediate revisions by the same user not shown)
Line 1: Line 1:
 
 
{| class="wikitable"
 
{| class="wikitable"
 
!Copyright notice <!-- don't remove! -->  
 
!Copyright notice <!-- don't remove! -->  
Line 23: Line 22:
 
Pareto (1812-1882), an engineer from an old Genoese family, was in
 
Pareto (1812-1882), an engineer from an old Genoese family, was in
 
exile at the time for political reasons.  His mother, Marie
 
exile at the time for political reasons.  His mother, Marie
M&eacute;tenier (1816-1889), was French, so that French was Pareto's
+
Métenier (1816-1889), was French, so that French was Pareto's
 
mother tongue; it was only after the family's return to the
 
mother tongue; it was only after the family's return to the
 
Piedmont in 1852 that he mastered Italian. He had two sisters who left no
 
Piedmont in 1852 that he mastered Italian. He had two sisters who left no
Line 36: Line 35:
 
donated his
 
donated his
 
library to the University of Lausanne in 1908.
 
library to the University of Lausanne in 1908.
He is buried at C&eacute;ligny near Geneva in Switzerland, where
+
He is buried at Céligny near Geneva in Switzerland, where
 
he had been residing since 1900.
 
he had been residing since 1900.
  
Line 53: Line 52:
 
Mathematical and Physical Sciences in 1867, and finally by the School
 
Mathematical and Physical Sciences in 1867, and finally by the School
 
of Applied Engineering of this University. He was awarded his
 
of Applied Engineering of this University. He was awarded his
engineering diploma following a thesis on ''La th&eacute;orie de l'&eacute;lasticit&eacute;
+
engineering diploma following a thesis on ''La théorie de l'élasticité
des corps solides et l'int&eacute;gration des e\'quations differentielles qui
+
des corps solides et l'intégration des équations differentielles qui
d&eacute;finissent l'&eacute;quilibre.''
+
définissent l'équilibre.''
  
 
<!-- \noindent -->
 
<!-- \noindent -->
Line 67: Line 66:
 
interested in economics and sociology.
 
interested in economics and sociology.
  
In 1874 he took part in the creation of the Soci&eacute;t&eacute; Adam Smith
+
In 1874 he took part in the creation of the Société Adam Smith
 
. During this  period he wrote several papers for
 
. During this  period he wrote several papers for
 
''L'economista'' from 1876, the ''Journal des Economistes'' from
 
''L'economista'' from 1876, the ''Journal des Economistes'' from
1887 and for the ''Monde &eacute;conomique'' and the ''Giornale degli
+
1887 and for the ''Monde économique'' and the ''Giornale degli
 
Economisti''. He also presented several communications at conferences.
 
Economisti''. He also presented several communications at conferences.
  
Line 79: Line 78:
 
He travelled extensively abroad, residing on
 
He travelled extensively abroad, residing on
 
occasion in France, Germany, Austria, England, Belgium and
 
occasion in France, Germany, Austria, England, Belgium and
Switzerland.  In 1891 in Switzerland  he met L&eacute;on Walras, whom
+
Switzerland.  In 1891 in Switzerland  he met Léon Walras, whom
 
he was to succeed in 1893 in the Chair of Political Economy at the
 
he was to succeed in 1893 in the Chair of Political Economy at the
 
University of Lausanne.
 
University of Lausanne.
Line 85: Line 84:
 
<!-- \noindent -->
 
<!-- \noindent -->
 
'''3.''' From 1893 on, he devoted himself to teaching and research.
 
'''3.''' From 1893 on, he devoted himself to teaching and research.
As an economist he was a follower of A. Cournot (q.v.) and L. Walras in
+
As an economist he was a follower of [[Cournot, Antoine Augustin|A. Cournot]] and L. Walras in
 
mathematical economics. His main innovation was a definition of
 
mathematical economics. His main innovation was a definition of
 
equilibrium (Pareto's optimum) which is still in use today.  But
 
equilibrium (Pareto's optimum) which is still in use today.  But
Line 101: Line 100:
 
<!-- \noindent -->
 
<!-- \noindent -->
  
''Cours d'&eacute;conomie politique'', Lausanne, Vol.1 (1896) and
+
''Cours d'économie politique'', Lausanne, Vol.1 (1896) and
 
Vol.2 (1897).
 
Vol.2 (1897).
  
Line 111: Line 110:
 
<!-- \noindent -->
 
<!-- \noindent -->
 
''Trattato di Sociologia'', Firenze, 1916 (French edition:
 
''Trattato di Sociologia'', Firenze, 1916 (French edition:
''Trait&eacute; de Sociologie'', Lausanne, 1917).
+
''Traité de Sociologie'', Lausanne, 1917).
  
 
In ''statistics''  Pareto worked in three areas:
 
In ''statistics''  Pareto worked in three areas:
Line 117: Line 116:
 
<!-- \noindent -->
 
<!-- \noindent -->
 
'''(a)''' Interpolation and fitting methods to which he devoted several
 
'''(a)''' Interpolation and fitting methods to which he devoted several
papers, in particular those in the ''Journal de la Soci&eacute;t&eacute;
+
papers, in particular those in the ''Journal de la Société
 
Statistique de Paris'', November 1897, and in the ''Zeitschrift
 
Statistique de Paris'', November 1897, and in the ''Zeitschrift
f&uuml;r schweizerische Statistik'', XXXV, 1899, as well as the ''Actes du IV&egrave;me Congr&egrave;s International de Psychologie''
+
für schweizerische Statistik'', XXXV, 1899, as well as the ''Actes du IVème Congrès International de Psychologie''
 
(Geneva, 1909).
 
(Geneva, 1909).
\smallskip
 
  
 
<!-- \noindent -->
 
<!-- \noindent -->
Line 127: Line 125:
 
calculation of pensions. He worked on these in 1905 in response to
 
calculation of pensions. He worked on these in 1905 in response to
 
a request from the employees of the Swiss Federal Railways.
 
a request from the employees of the Swiss Federal Railways.
\smallskip
 
  
 
The main works which he published in the two areas (a) and (b) have
 
The main works which he published in the two areas (a) and (b) have
 
been republished in Pareto (1989), where his
 
been republished in Pareto (1989), where his
paper  "Sur les fonctions g&eacute;n&eacute;ratrices d'Abel" in pure
+
paper  "Sur les fonctions génératrices d'Abel" in pure
mathematics, published in Kronecker's "Journal f&uuml;r die reine und
+
mathematics, published in Kronecker's "Journal für die reine und
 
angewandte Mathematik '', '''110''' (1892), 290-323, is also to be found.
 
angewandte Mathematik '', '''110''' (1892), 290-323, is also to be found.
\smallskip
 
  
 
<!-- \noindent -->
 
<!-- \noindent -->
Line 158: Line 154:
 
distributions: Pareto himself had attempted to develop probabilistic models
 
distributions: Pareto himself had attempted to develop probabilistic models
 
as early as 1896 (see Pareto, 1964, supplements to Vol.2, pp.416-419).
 
as early as 1896 (see Pareto, 1964, supplements to Vol.2, pp.416-419).
Thirty years later Maurice Fr&eacute;chet (q.v.) was to perfect Pareto's model.
+
Thirty years later [[Fréchet, Maurice|Maurice Fréchet]] was to perfect Pareto's model.
  
 
The most profound reason for the frequency with which Pareto
 
The most profound reason for the frequency with which Pareto
distributions appear was given in 1935 by Paul L&eacute;vy (1937), namely
+
distributions appear was given in 1935 by Paul Lévy (1937), namely
 
that stable
 
that stable
 
distributions, other than the Laplace-Gauss ( Normal) distribution, exhibit  
 
distributions, other than the Laplace-Gauss ( Normal) distribution, exhibit  
Line 181: Line 177:
 
Gaussian (Normal) distribution and its domain of attraction in statistics.
 
Gaussian (Normal) distribution and its domain of attraction in statistics.
 
Unfortunately it only earned him the lack of understanding and
 
Unfortunately it only earned him the lack of understanding and
hostility of his peers, in particular F.Y. Edgeworth (q.v.).
+
hostility of his peers, in particular [[Edgeworth, Francis Ysidro|F.Y. Edgeworth]].
  
  
Line 187: Line 183:
 
{|
 
{|
 
|-
 
|-
|valign="top"|{{Ref|1}}||valign="top"|  Pareto, V. (1964). ''Cours d'&Eacute;conomie Politique'', Droz, Geneva. [This is a new edition by G.H. Bousquet and G. Busino.]  
+
|valign="top"|{{Ref|1}}||valign="top"|  Pareto, V. (1964). ''Cours d'économie Politique'', Droz, Geneva. [This is a new edition by G.H. Bousquet and G. Busino.]  
 
|-
 
|-
|valign="top"|{{Ref|2}}||valign="top"|  Pareto, V. (1965). ''&Eacute;crits sur la courbe de r&eacute;partition de la richesse''.  Droz, Geneva. [Collected with commentary by  G. Busino.]   
+
|valign="top"|{{Ref|2}}||valign="top"|  Pareto, V. (1965). ''Écrits sur la courbe de répartition de la richesse''.  Droz, Geneva. [Collected with commentary by  G. Busino.]   
 
|-
 
|-
|valign="top"|{{Ref|3}}||valign="top"|  Pareto, V. (1989). ''Statistique et &Eacute;conomie math&eacute;matique''. Droz, Geneva. [Preface by Ren&eacute; Roy.]   
+
|valign="top"|{{Ref|3}}||valign="top"|  Pareto, V. (1989). ''Statistique et économie mathématique''. Droz, Geneva. [Preface by René Roy.]   
 
|-
 
|-
|valign="top"|{{Ref|4}}||valign="top"|  L&eacute;vy, P. (1937). ''Th&eacute;orie de l'addition des variables  al&eacute;atoires''.  Gauthier-Villars,  Paris.
+
|valign="top"|{{Ref|4}}||valign="top"|  Lévy, P. (1937). ''Théorie de l'addition des variables  aléatoires''.  Gauthier-Villars,  Paris.
 
|-
 
|-
 
|}
 
|}

Latest revision as of 08:05, 10 March 2024

Copyright notice
This article Vilfredo Federigo Samaso Pareto was adapted from an original article by Marc Barbut, which appeared in StatProb: The Encyclopedia Sponsored by Statistics and Probability Societies. The original article ([http://statprob.com/encyclopedia/VilfredoFederigoSamasoPARETO.html StatProb Source], Local Files: pdf | tex) is copyrighted by the author(s), the article has been donated to Encyclopedia of Mathematics, and its further issues are under Creative Commons Attribution Share-Alike License'. All pages from StatProb are contained in the Category StatProb.

Vilfredo Federigo Samaso PARETO

b. 15 July 1848 - d. 19 August 1923


Summary Pareto showed empirically in 1896 that the distribution of income was asymptotically $x^{-\alpha}$, thus discovering the very first case of a stable non-Gaussian probability distribution.

Vilfredo Pareto was born in Paris, where his father, the Marquis Raffaele Pareto (1812-1882), an engineer from an old Genoese family, was in exile at the time for political reasons. His mother, Marie Métenier (1816-1889), was French, so that French was Pareto's mother tongue; it was only after the family's return to the Piedmont in 1852 that he mastered Italian. He had two sisters who left no progeny.

His first wife whom he married in 1889 was a Russian aristocrat, Alexandrina (Dina) Bakounine, who left him in 1900. He remarried to Jeanne Regis, a Frenchwoman with whom he had been living for twenty years, two months before his death. As he had no children, he left his fairly considerable fortune to her, having earlier donated his library to the University of Lausanne in 1908. He is buried at Céligny near Geneva in Switzerland, where he had been residing since 1900.

His life, public, intellectual and professional is fairly neatly divided into three phases.

1. The period from his birth till 1870 was the formative phase. This was basically scientific and technical, although Pareto learned Greek and Latin by himself and became a discriminating connoisseur of these languages. He first attended the Leardi Technical Institute at Casale Monferrato (Piedmont) from 1859-1861, then the Royal Technical Institute of Turin (1861-1864). This was followed by the University of Turin (Torino), where he obtained his degree in the Mathematical and Physical Sciences in 1867, and finally by the School of Applied Engineering of this University. He was awarded his engineering diploma following a thesis on La théorie de l'élasticité des corps solides et l'intégration des équations differentielles qui définissent l'équilibre.

2. From 1870 to 1873, Pareto worked as an engineer on the Italian railways, then in 1873 joined a firm building railway material at San Giovanni Valdarno in Tuscany. He managed this firm from 1880 to 1890, becoming a consultant between 1890 and 1893. It was during this period, when he faced the economic and social problems of managing the firm that he became vitally interested in economics and sociology.

In 1874 he took part in the creation of the Société Adam Smith . During this period he wrote several papers for L'economista from 1876, the Journal des Economistes from 1887 and for the Monde économique and the Giornale degli Economisti. He also presented several communications at conferences.

He was resolutely in favour of a liberal economy, but he was also a pacifist and an anti-colonialist. He stood for election to the Chamber of Deputies but was not successful.

He travelled extensively abroad, residing on occasion in France, Germany, Austria, England, Belgium and Switzerland. In 1891 in Switzerland he met Léon Walras, whom he was to succeed in 1893 in the Chair of Political Economy at the University of Lausanne.

3. From 1893 on, he devoted himself to teaching and research. As an economist he was a follower of A. Cournot and L. Walras in mathematical economics. His main innovation was a definition of equilibrium (Pareto's optimum) which is still in use today. But Pareto valued theory only insofar as it stood the test of reality; it was one of the reasons for his interest in statistics and for his work in this field.

As a sociologist, he was convinced that economic facts were inseparable from the society which engendered them. Thus, from 1897 until his retirement in 1911, he taught sociology as well.

It was during this period that his three main books were published:


Cours d'économie politique, Lausanne, Vol.1 (1896) and Vol.2 (1897).

Manuale di economia politica con una introduzione alla scienza sociale, Milano, 1906 (French translation: Manuel d'Economie politique, Paris, 1909).

Trattato di Sociologia, Firenze, 1916 (French edition: Traité de Sociologie, Lausanne, 1917).

In statistics Pareto worked in three areas:

(a) Interpolation and fitting methods to which he devoted several papers, in particular those in the Journal de la Société Statistique de Paris, November 1897, and in the Zeitschrift für schweizerische Statistik, XXXV, 1899, as well as the Actes du IVème Congrès International de Psychologie (Geneva, 1909).

(b) Actuarial studies on mutual insurance systems and the calculation of pensions. He worked on these in 1905 in response to a request from the employees of the Swiss Federal Railways.

The main works which he published in the two areas (a) and (b) have been republished in Pareto (1989), where his paper "Sur les fonctions génératrices d'Abel" in pure mathematics, published in Kronecker's "Journal für die reine und angewandte Mathematik , 110 (1892), 290-323, is also to be found.

(c) But it was mainly his discovery in 1895 of the ``Distribution curve for wealth and incomes" that Pareto is renowned as a statistician. He showed empirically that the observed distribution of incomes, like that of wealth was well fitted by theoretical distributions of the type

$$ Pr(X > x) = \frac {K}{(x + c)^\alpha}, x \geq x_0, \tag{1}$$

$K$ and $c$ being respectively parameters of scale and location while the exponent $\alpha$, for the series studied by Pareto, takes values between 1 and 2 (see Pareto, 1964, 1965).

Later, this kind of distribution was found to arise in various fields, not only in the social sciences, but also in the natural and physical sciences. Various probabilistic models lead to such distributions: Pareto himself had attempted to develop probabilistic models as early as 1896 (see Pareto, 1964, supplements to Vol.2, pp.416-419). Thirty years later Maurice Fréchet was to perfect Pareto's model.

The most profound reason for the frequency with which Pareto distributions appear was given in 1935 by Paul Lévy (1937), namely that stable distributions, other than the Laplace-Gauss ( Normal) distribution, exhibit the asymptotic behaviour of type (1), with $0 < \alpha < 2$.

Further, when conditions for convergence to the Normal distribution in the Central Limit Theorem do not apply, namely when dealing with independent identically-distributed random summands whose large values have a non-negligible probability (heavy tailed distributions), if these distributions have tail behaviour asymptotically of type (1), then a Central Limit Theorem result still holds, with stable law of exponent $\alpha$ figuring as the limit law, rather than the Normal.

It is thus to Pareto that belongs the immense credit for breaking the almost total monopoly of the Gaussian (Normal) distribution and its domain of attraction in statistics. Unfortunately it only earned him the lack of understanding and hostility of his peers, in particular F.Y. Edgeworth.


References

[1] Pareto, V. (1964). Cours d'économie Politique, Droz, Geneva. [This is a new edition by G.H. Bousquet and G. Busino.]
[2] Pareto, V. (1965). Écrits sur la courbe de répartition de la richesse. Droz, Geneva. [Collected with commentary by G. Busino.]
[3] Pareto, V. (1989). Statistique et économie mathématique. Droz, Geneva. [Preface by René Roy.]
[4] Lévy, P. (1937). Théorie de l'addition des variables aléatoires. Gauthier-Villars, Paris.



Reprinted with permission from Christopher Charles Heyde and Eugene William Seneta (Editors), Statisticians of the Centuries, Springer-Verlag Inc., New York, USA.

How to Cite This Entry:
Pareto, Vilfredo Federigo Samaso. Encyclopedia of Mathematics. URL: http://encyclopediaofmath.org/index.php?title=Pareto,_Vilfredo_Federigo_Samaso&oldid=39243